|
Continue reading ETI Views and News at
econtech.com,
or download a
printer-friendly version.
Follow us on Twitter @EconAndTech
|
An emerging new business model for wireless service – "Bring Your Own Device"
|
|
Back in the 1980s when cellular was in its infancy, when cell phone weights were stated in pounds rather than ounces and when most came with automobiles attached to them, the full retail price of these early handsets ran upwards of $1,000; even more for what passed for "portable" units that needed to be hauled around in a small suitcase.
To make matters worse, just a few years earlier in its so-called Computer Inquiry II ruling, the FCC prohibited carriers from bundling customer premises equipment (CPE) with telephone service, so that the only means by which the carriers could place cellphones in the hands of potential customers was to "sell" the phones to them. But as the newly minted wireless carriers quickly discovered, at $1,000 to $2,000 a pop, the price of a cellphone presented a formidable – seemingly insurmountable – barrier to widespread consumer acceptance of this new technology. The carriers' solution was to offer these expensive devices for sale to their customers at prices that were set well below the carriers' costs. The cost of these "handset subsidies" would then be recovered by setting monthly cellular access and per-minute airtime usage rates well in excess of the carriers' costs for fulfilling these functions.
This approach to pricing was hardly a novel concept – Polaroid had used it, pricing cameras below their cost and making up the shortfall through the sale of firm; Gillette had used this approach for razors and blades, and more recently, inkjet printer manufacturers like HP and Epson have adopted a pricing model whereby they lose money on the selling price of their printers but make it up by setting highly profitable prices for ink. The economic theory underlying this so-called "platform pricing" strategy is fairly straightforward: The consumer must purchase the "platform" product – the Polaroid camera, the razor, the inkjet printer, the cellphone – as a threshold to purchasing the dependent product or service – the film, the razorblade, the ink cartridge, or wireless usage. Since the purchases of the platform product and the dependent product are necessarily sequential, one needs to get the platform product into the hands of consumers as a precondition for creating any derived demand for the dependent product.
This type of pricing strategy, however, does have several serious pitfalls. First, the provider needs to be reasonably assured that profits generated from sales of the dependent product will be sufficient to permit it to recover the subsidy of the platform product, at least in the aggregate if not from each and every individual customer. Which in turn requires that the provider of the platform product be in a position to exert sufficient control over the market for the dependent product so as to prevent the customer from acquiring that dependent product from another source, one that would not need to set its price so as to recover the initial platform subsidy. In many cases, this control is acquired via patent – Polaroid cameras would only work with Polaroid film – or by some other device to foreclose "leakage" -- the purchase of the dependent product from another source at a lower price, one that does not include the recovery of the initial platform subsidy.
Platform-type pricing requires only that, in aggregate, the platform subsidy be recovered through profits derived from sales of the dependent product. As long as enough customers purchase enough ink cartridges, the printer manufacturer can recover the shortfall in printer prices, even though some customers individually may not ever buy enough ink to recover the manufacturer's loss resulting from that particular customer's printer purchase. Initially, wireless carriers had adopted a similar approach – i.e., looking only to the profitability of their pricing model in aggregate, not with respect to each individual customer.
But around a dozen years ago, the major wireless carriers modified their pricing model by adopting measures aimed both at limiting their customers' ability to take the (subsidized) handset to a competing wireless carrier for service – a capability that the FCC had affirmatively sought to facilitate when, in 2003 and after years of wrangling over the details, it finally required that wireless telephone numbers be made "portable" so that customers could change their service provider without being forced also to change their wireless phone number. The first of these two measures was accomplished through a software "lock" that was programmed into the operating system of the handset itself. The "lock" prevented the customer from activating wireless service on a carrier network other than the one from which the handset had been purchased (the handset could still be used for roaming on another carriers' networks). The second approach was to require that customers enter into a contract, whose effect was to force the customer to retain service for a specified period of time – typically two years – or be subject to an early termination fee (ETF) if the service is discontinued prior to the completion of the contract term,
Handset locking and term contracts with early termination fees are, to be sure, something of a "belt and suspenders" strategy, and have not been without controversy – particularly when, by the mid-2000s, the wholesale prices of many wireless handsets had dropped to the $50 to $100 range. From the standpoint of an individual purchaser of wireless service, the dollar value of the handset "subsidy" was often overwhelmed by the huge markup on the monthly recurring access charges and the various voice, text and data usage rates to which the customer was subject long after the "subsidy" had been fully recovered by the carrier. This point was compellingly demonstrated in testimony by ETI's President Dr. Lee Selwyn at an FCC en banc hearing held in June of 2008 on the subject of wireless early termination fees.
Dr. Selwyn provided the FCC with evidence adduced at trial in a class action lawsuit against Sprint that had been presented to the jury a few days before the FCC hearing. That evidence indicated that Sprint bases its revenue forecasts on the assumption that customers will remain on the Sprint network for an average of 60 months. This is an average customer life – some will terminate early, others will remain on the network for well beyond the 60 month average. Based upon this 60-month customer life and using Sprint cost and revenue data for 1999-2005, Dr. Selwyn provided the following analysis of the costs, resulting gross revenues, and gross profit margin being realized as a result of Sprint's platform pricing model:
Weighted monthly Average Revenue per Unit (ARPU) over the period 1999-2005 |
$ 61.09 |
Average customer length of service (Sprint assumption) |
60 months |
Revenue per customer over 60-month average life |
$3,665.61 |
Weighted Average Cost per Gross Addition (CPGA) including marketing and handset subsidies (2000-2005) |
$357.40 |
Gross profit per customer net of CPGA |
$3,308.21 |
CPGA as % of Lifetime Revenue per Customer |
9.75% |
Several key conclusions can be drawn from this analysis, all of which lead to the inevitable conclusion that customers are paying many multiples of the "handset subsidy" they receive (if indeed there is any subsidy at all) over the life of their relationship with the wireless service provider:
- While the recurring and usage rate levels may be designed to permit recovery of the handset subsidy, having established the customer's willingness-to-pay at that price point, the subsidy-recovering rates remain in effect even after the full amount of the subsidy has been recovered by the carrier which, in Sprint's case, was after only about seven months..
- When viewed in terms of the lifetime cost of the wireless service, customers are forced to pay far more for their handsets than they would if handsets were fully unbundled from wireless service.
- From the carriers' perspective, the practice of subsidizing handsets and overpricing access, usage, and overage fees is highly profitable in aggregate, and does not require either handset locking or contracts with early termination fees.
Unbundling handsets from wireless service
Several months ago (Views and News, August 2012) we reported that certain smaller wireless service providers – which had not cut a deal with Apple to market the iPhone – were offering unsubsidized or "bring your own" iPhone pricing plans at substantially lower recurring monthly rates when compared with the bundled iPhone and service plans being offered by AT&T and Verizon. At identical (subsidized) iPhone prices of $199 and recurring service prices of $110 per month with a two-year contract, the total price for an iPhone 4S plus two years of service from each of the "big 2" carriers was $2,839. At the other extreme, Virgin Mobile, which resells Sprint wireless service under an MVNO ("Mobile Virtual Network Operator") arrangement, is offering the iPhone 4S at its full and unsubsidized $649 retail price, but is charging only $35 per month for service (and is requiring no contract). Over a two-year period, a Virgin customer would have paid only $1,489, a savings of more than $1,300 over the AT&T or Verizon price points. Put differently, the AT&T or Verizon customer will have paid roughly triple the $649 full retail price for an iPhone 4S in exchange for the $450 up-front subsidy that the "big 2" carriers offer. If one thinks of the handset subsidy ($450) as the principal to be financed through an instalment purchase and the additional monthly charge ($75) as the monthly payment, that works out to an effective simple annual interest rate of roughly 195%! Obviously, unless one is sorely strapped for cash, this deal is perhaps one of the most costly consumer finance charge arrangements that exists anywhere, one that would put Slick Louie the loanshark to shame.
Are handset subsidies still necessary?
The major wireless carriers maintain their platform pricing and subsidized handset pricing strategies because they are highly profitable, not necessarily because the subsidies are still needed to attract customers. Indeed, there is compelling evidence that such subsidies are no longer required in what has become a highly-mature wireless market.
Wireless phones are as ubiquitous today as wireline phones were a decade or more ago, and in fact there are nearly three times as many wireless phones as wireline phones now in use in the US. Consumers have demonstrated a willingness to pay full price for communications devices capable of accessing the Internet – from desktop computers and laptops of the past decade to the hottest new tablets. Indeed, while both AT&T and Verizon offer wireless data service specifically for iPads and even sell iPads in their retail stores,
neither company subsidizes the iPad purchase or requires a contract for iPad wireless data service. Apple recently reported having sold more than 100-million iPads.
Smaller wireless MVNOs have already rolled out BYOD trials. Ting, an MVNO reselling Sprint service, will activate customer-owned Sprint-compatible devices on its network for just $6/month without an activation fee or term contract. Users pay only for the usage they actually generate, and are moved up and down the Ting usage tiers without penalty. If a customer activates more than one device on the same account, each device shares the pool of minutes, texts, and data. Such plans result in substantially lower monthly costs for wireless users when compared to AT&T and Verizon.
Will the larger carriers be pressured by competitors like Ting, Cricket and Virgin to offer unbundled BYOD pricing? That depends upon how successful the smaller providers are in convincing customers that they need to look to lifetime price rather than just up-front payment. But as the smartphone and tablet markets converge – smartphones are getting larger while tablets are getting smaller – the carriers may confront pressure from their own treatment of tablets to adopt BYOD pricing options across all of their services.
For more information, contact Lee L. Selwyn at lselwyn@econtech.com
Read the rest of Views and News, November 2012.
|
|
|
About ETI. Founded in 1972, Economics and Technology, Inc. is a leading research and consulting firm specializing in telecommunications regulation and policy, litigation support, taxation, service procurement, and negotiation. ETI serves a wide range of telecom industry stakeholders in the US and abroad, including telecommunications carriers, attorneys and their clients, consumer advocates, state and local governments, regulatory agencies, and large corporate, institutional and government purchasers of telecom services. |
|
|